

Our Call to Battle
by
William Krehm
The Wall Street Journal (26/02, “Obamas School
Choice” editorial) minced no words on the matter of
opening the best schooling to talented children, no
matter how humble their parents earning-powers. And
wasnt the president a winged instance of that principle
practiced?
But let us return to the editorial, remembering that
the WSJs basic purpose is hardly to champion the
nations underdogs no matter how talented: “President
Obama made education a big part of his speech Tuesday
night, complete with a stirring call for reform. So well
be curious to see how he handles the dismaying attempt
by Democrats in Congress to crush education choice for
poor kids in the District of Columbia.
“The omnibus spending bill now before the House
includes language designed to kill the Opportunity
Scholarship Program offering poor students vouchers to
opt out of rotten public schools.”
Of course, it is an omnibus bill operating on the
same principle that results in people without the
necessary cash or private coaches traveling in public
transport or in shoes in bad repair. The “law of
averaging.” However, talent does not average out, and
when it happens it should be respected and treated as a
national resource.
At risk of repeating ourselves necessary because
those who should be speaking up in our southern
neighbors legislature are no exception: they get the
“issue” out of the way by disregarding it, or slitting
its throat.
Inevitable because of the constraint of available
time? Then they as we, since there are no haloes around
Canadas head in this as in other vital matters seem to
believe not that a knowledge of history would save us
time. But rather that is “saved” by walking over the
faces and hopes, of an elite of talent already sifted
for quality by the first of lifes tests. That is
particularly inept because human investment has been
identified as the best investment a government can make.
The lesson was purchased at the greatest cost ever
paid for a lesson in both history and economics it was
one of the most important lessons to come out of World
War II. Suppressing that lesson, and pretending that it
does not exist, cannot serve a helpful end.
But part of due retribution is for those who have
ignored crucial bits of our history be condemned to have
it repeated to them through every available channel.
Boring that may be, but we must at whatever cost let in
a few rays of light in on such survival matters. COMER
is putting on its battle jackets again and reorganizing
to bring the survival message at stake in this matter to
the public and government levels so that we can get ear
of in both Canada and the United States. We are
reorganizing both our publications and our membership
towards this end. And here is the suppressed message
that ignores a simple accountancy solution that got the
United States out of a major crisis in 1996, and Canada
to a lesser degree in 2002. And here are the details of
the solution already tried and found workable in those
years and now has only to be extended to human capital
to get the country and the world out of a threatened
melt-down without the government taking over a single
bone-rotten bank, or the worst of its portfolio of lost
gambles. Here is the suppressed bit of history that we
must never stop retelling:
At the end of WWII Washington dispatched hundreds of
economists to Japan and Germany to predict how long it
would be for the two leading axis powers to regain their
powers as key world traders. In 1961 some 16 years later
one of these economists wrote a paper in which he stated
it was amazing how wrong he and his colleagues had been.
And the reason, he concluded, was they had concentrated
on physical destruction. and overlooked that the highly
gifted, educated, and disciplined work forces of those
two leading Axis lands had come through the war
essentially intact. His name was Theodore Schultz and
for a few years he was feted and prized for having
identified one of the great lessons of WWII: that
investment in human capital is one of the most
profitable investments a government can make.
Eventually this had great consequences of the way
governments kept their books: private and corporate
taxpayers were always required to enter every
transaction in their ledger twice once for the initial
cost in cash or debt of the government and once for the
current value of the physical assets of that investment.
That was known as “accrual” or “capital” accountancy and
that initial cost was “amortized” over the foreseeable
useful life of the market value that was “depreciated”
over at least approximately a similar period.
But that was not the way governments kept their
own books. They did in fact “amortize” their
cash cost over the foreseeable life of the asset value
of the investment, but the asset value itself was “depreciated”
in a single year, and at the end of that year
assigned a value of a token dollar. This had two
resounding results. It produce a capital debit on the
government books that was not necessarily there, and it
opened the possibility of lucrative privatizations for
the well-connected. If you have bridges, raw land or
buildings, and highways carried at one dollar, you can
buy at “a thousand times book” and resell for a crazy
profit and go to church with the gait of a
philanthropist.
That convenient way of sparing many in the saddle of
the risk of saddle-sores, was discontinued under much
disarray at the beginning of 1996 in the US and very
partially some six years later to a lesser extent in
Canada. By the 1970s the banks had recovered from their
devastating losses that they had gotten themselves in
during the 1920s. By the time F.D. Roosevelt was
inaugurated for his first term in 1933, 9,000 banks had
closed their doors, and the first thing the new
president did was to declare a bank moratorium during
which all banks shut their doors. When they reopened for
business the Glass-Steagall law had prohibited them from
acquiring interests in “non-banking financial pillars.”
In those innocent days that covered only stock
brokerages, insurance and mortgage corporations. The
reason? The Great Depression of the 1920s had been
brought on by the banks being allowed to take over
non-banking financial companies and in that way getting
control of the cash reserves needed for the acquired
companies own businesses. And once that happened that
served the banks as “legal tender” base for their own
banking multiplier. But many of these other pillars were
already charging interest, the reserves from legal
tender become “near-money,” since in that case they move
inversely with the rate of interest set by the central
bank. So that not only left the acquired companies in
potential trouble, but loaded the banks with a growing
skyscraper of interest-bearing money of varied quality
as the skyscraper of bank growth went up compelled to
keep on rising in order not to collapse, with the
element of risk supposedly “insured” against by
derivative devices that would cause a first-year maths
student to be kicked out of the course. It was like a
crazy skyscraper that was compelled to rise ever faster
with an elevator that could only go up, never down.
It Should Take
More than “Insurance” to Evoke Trust
Its soundness was guaranteed by insurance companies
on the basis of derivative “swaps.” The details of such
derivative constructs were banned from discussion at
practically all international economics congresses in
recent years that we have attended. But quite apart from
the dubious assurance of the solidity derived from the
exponential mathematical series that is the heart of the
atomic bomb, John Maynard Keynes who died in 1946
pointed out years before his death the absurdity of
trying to deduce from the experience of the past what
will work in the ever-changing future on the basis of
any mathematical or other assurance dubbed “insurance.”
There had been a protection against the dominant
power this would otherwise give banks whose basic
revenue is interest rates. That had been the statutory
reserves that required the banks deposit with the
central bank a proportion of the deposits they receive
from the public. By raising that proportion that lowered
the net amount of deposits left to the banks to lend out
themselves, this limited the effective power of the
banks over the economy. But that was done away with
systematically. Whenever the International Monetary Fund
is called in by a country for help for its lack of
foreign currency, the IMF lays down as a condition the
end of the statutory reserves. The net result of such a
position is to leave the benchmark interest rate set by
the central banks in a monopolist position in managing
the course of the economy. It raised interest rates to
the position of “dominant revenue,” so well described by
the late great French economist FranÁois Perroux. It was
the revenue of the group with monopolist power, by its
rate of growth both of its rate and absolute volume that
is taken as a reliable index of societys well-being as a
whole.
Meanwhile, the “near-money” interest-bearing
short-term funds taken over by the banks as money-base
for their bank-money creation, which every takeover of
near-money involved as bank money-creation supposedly
insured by derivative swaps provided a bogus insurance
based on an illiterate notion of what mathematics can
do.
There is a howling need to bring professional
mathematicians to teach economists and economics
students the empirical content of any mathematical
device is zero. Its analytical powers are what are
unbounded. Contemporary economists that do not
distinguish the two are at the basis of the current
collapse of our monetary systems.
The ultimate bankruptcy of official economics today
is that it has cast off all reference to the lessons of
our own history and economic experience. Had this not
been done and removed beyond all serious criticism, a
completely prepaid package of capital resources
would be recognized available to almost any of the
developed countries in the world today.
By 1991 the adventures of the US banks in taking over
the mortgage trusts (Savings & Loans) in the US had led
to many of the banks losing most or more than most of
their capital. The Bank for International Settlements a
world central bankers war-room dedicated to bringing the
world banking systems back to the freedom of the 1920s
that ushered in the Great Depression had declared the
debt of developed countries risk-free and thus requiring
no down-payment for banks to acquire. As a result
Canadian banks increased their holdings of such debt by
400% to a total of $100 billion held entirely on the
cuff, nothing down. At the same time the manager of BIS
decided that there was to be no trifling with anything
different from what they chose to call “zero inflation”
to be achieved by pushing interest rates “high enough to
do the job.” The “job” was atrociously defined since
nobody moving from a town of 20,000 population to New
York expects the cost of living to remain the same. How
then could it when humanity as a whole is making just
such a move, quite apart from the technological
revolution that makes anybody without a university
education of the proper sort less and less employable?
As a result, BISs oversight almost brought down the
world banking system. What saved it was the decision of
the Clinton government that the days of high interest
rates were over, to get around that one they finally
listened to their auditing officials and decided that
the time had come to bring in accrual accountancy and
“depreciate” the physical assets of government not in a
single year but in roughly over the same period as the
cash or financed cost of a capital project was being
“amortized.” Doing this and extending the treatment to
1959 turned up almost $1.25 trillion of additional net
worth prepaid.
That equipped governments to deal with physical
investment except, of course, such government
investments were financed in recent decades not with the
Bank of Canada, where such costs would have been
nominal, but through the private banking system. What
still remains on our government books as current
spending is human investments, that on the basis of
Washingtons costly researches, came up with Theodore
Schultzs astounding conclusion supported in particular
by Japans imaginatively planned reconstruction of its
economy from a textile-based one with most of its raw
materials coming from abroad to a
heavy-machinery-building economy where a vastly
increased proportion of the gross income would remain in
the country, Even during recessions the government would
choose a single company in each of the new engineering
lines to proceed with innovations that would at the next
economic revival become available to the entire
industry. You need brilliant, educated, talented
managers to develop well in advance ideas like that.
The
Suppression of Schultz and His Law
The detail pertinent to the present deepening current
crisis of the world is with the suppression of Schultzs
conclusion for it was not simply “forgotten” we still
have a vast amount of government investment in human
capital already invested and completely paid for that is
on the government books not even at a token dollar. And
yet, to treat human investment on government
books for what it is after the job already done on the
physical investments of government is a cookie-cutter
affair. A cook used to reading recipes could handle the
issue.
What would this be worth to the nation? Let us make
the comparison of the US shift to accrual accountancy
for its physical investments in 1996. The official
calculation was at the time just under $1.25 trillion.
Even the movement of the price level over a 13-year
period for most of it, and another 37 years for a bit of
it, would let us, say, double the figure for bringing in
accrual accountancy to government investment in human
capital today. But that calculation was based on
continuing to use the private banks instead of the
Federal Reserve for the financing of it. In Canada our
central bank was nationalized primarily for such
purposes. But it was no lapse of memory that prevented
the use of the central banks in either country in
shifting to accrual accountancy in their different
degrees. This time that is part of the deal, since we
are going to have to battle hard to get any of it
through. That would bring the US figure for a similar
job today up to at least $3 trillion and Canada to the
usual 1/10 of the American statistic or $300 billion.
But there are some unusual features of human
investment. Its expenditure is in itself an investment.
The children of better-educated parents for social as
well as strictly genetic reasons tend to be better
educated and healthier, and better adjusted. And their
children, thanks to the same factors and opportunities,
equally so. So instead of having spending, the result is
more like further investment. Whatever England spent on
teaching Isaac Newton algebra is still bringing in
income to Britain in millions of ways today.
Obviously all levels of government will have to be
included in this scheme for they contribute to the
investments and hence are entitled to a participation in
the returns. What sense then does President Obamas
wasting both our time and bringing on a further
debasement of the legal tender trying to straighten out
the banking system en route?
On that point The New York Times (27/02,
“Failing Upward At the Fed” by Floyd Norris) reports:
“Sometimes nothing succeeds like failure.
“In his speech to Congress, the president asked the
legislators to quickly reform financial regulation.
Representative Barney Frank, the chairman of the House
Financial Services Committee, told me after the speech
that he expected to pass a bill this year to make the
Fed into a systemic regulator, able to take jurisdiction
over any financial institution if it threatens the
financial system.
“Books will be written on the failure of the Fed in
the last cycle. It decided that it did not have to worry
itself over rising asset prices. So it stood by, first
in the technology stock bubble, then in the house
bubble. It saw credit getting excessively loose, and
leverage piling up, but comforted us with the assurances
that if there was a bubble, the Fed knew how to clean up
after it burst, principally by cutting interest rates.
“It championed letting the shadow financial system
grow without oversight, and shied away from doing
anything about highly risky mortgages.
“Perhaps most important, the Fed and other regulators
had no idea of how much risk they had allowed into the
system. They knew that the various financial innovations
were designed to let banks make more money without being
required to put up more capital, but they did not figure
out that meant that the capital there might be
inadequate. They threw up their hands at the complexity
of it all, and said banks could use their own models to
assess risk.
“In sum, the Fed thought it had learned the lessons
of the 1930s, but it had not learned the lesson of the
1920s, that allowing assets asset prices to soar to
absurdly leveraged heights could lead to a collapse as
the need to repay loans forced sales that drove prices
lower, resulting in the need to repay more loans, and on
and on.
“Even now, the banks being bailed out have not been
required to detail the toxic securities they own.
Without that information, it is impossible for even
sophisticated analysts to assess whether each bank has
taken all the write-downs it should. That is one
reason banks are hesitant to trust each other.”
And this is what the Obama regime has opted for
rather than using $3 trillion of already invested
capital that has financed the most productive investment
a government can make cannot be just a slip in judgment,
but a choice of loyalty. The prepaid human capital spent
in retraining work forces, sending talented kids to
college, cleaning up the environment will run up no debt
but lead to a softening of the depression that is
already upon us, and equip the professionals and workers
for an early revival.
This is what the coming Obama crisis will be about.
It will take more than charm and good intentions to get
humanity out of the chapters of disaster that are
blowing out of Washington.
That is why COMER is getting into campaign form once
more.
|
Copyright © 2009 COMER Publications. |
|
|
Reproduced by permissions of |
|
|
COMER
Publications |
|
|
Source |
|
|
www.COMER.org |
|
 |