

The Language of Looting
By MICHAEL HUDSON
"Banking shares began to plunge Friday morning after
Senator Dodd, the Connecticut Democrat who is chairman
of the banking committee, said in an interview with
Bloomberg Television that he was concerned the
government might end up nationalizing some lenders “at
least for a short time.” Several other prominent
policy makers – including Alan Greenspan, the former
chairman of the Federal Reserve, and Senator Lindsey
Graham of South Carolina – have echoed that view
recently.”
--Eric Dash, “Growing Worry on Rescue Takes a Toll on
Banks,” The New York Times, February 20, 2009
How
is it that Alan Greenspan, free-market lobbyist for
Wall Street, recently announced that he favored
nationalization of America’s banks – and indeed, mainly
the biggest and most powerful? Has the old disciple of
Ayn Rand gone Red in the night? Surely not.
The answer is that the rhetoric of “free markets,”
“nationalization” and even “socialism” (as in
“socializing the losses”) has been turned into the
language of deception to help the financial sector
mobilize government power to support its own special
privileges. Having undermined the economy at large, Wall
Street’s public relations think tanks are now
dismantling the language itself.
Exactly what does “a free market” mean? Is it what the
classical economists advocated – a market free from
monopoly power, business fraud, political insider
dealing and special privileges for vested interests – a
market protected by the rise in public regulation from
the Sherman Anti-Trust law of 1890 to the Glass-Steagall
Act and other New Deal legislation? Or is it a market
free for predators to exploit victims without
public regulation or economic policemen – the kind of
free-for-all market that the Federal Reserve and
Security and Exchange Commission (SEC) have created over
the past decade or so? It seems incredible that people
should accept today’s neoliberal idea of “market
freedom” in the sense of neutering government watchdogs,
Alan Greenspan-style, letting Angelo Mozilo at
Countrywide, Hank Greenberg at AIG, Bernie Madoff,
Citibank, Bear Stearns and Lehman Brothers loot without
hindrance or sanction, plunge the economy into crisis
and then use Treasury bailout money to pay the highest
salaries and bonuses in U.S. history.
Terms that are the antithesis of “free market” also are
being turned into the opposite of what they historically
have meant. Take today’s discussions about nationalizing
the banks. For over a century nationalization has meant
public takeover of monopolies or other sectors to
operate them in the public interest rather than leaving
them so special interests. But when neoliberals use the
word “nationalization” they mean a bailout, a government
giveaway to the financial interests.
Doublethink and doubletalk with regard to
“nationalizing” or “socializing” the banks and other
sectors is a travesty of political and economic
discussion from the 17th through mid-20th centuries.
Society’s basic grammar of thought, the vocabulary to
discuss political and economic topics, is being turned
inside-out in an effort to ward off discussion of the
policy solutions posed by the classical economists and
political philosophers that made Western civilization
“Western.”
Today’s clash of civilization is not really with the
Orient; it is with our own past, with the Enlightenment
itself and its evolution into classical political
economy and Progressive Era social reforms aimed at
freeing society from the surviving trammels of European
feudalism. What we are seeing is propaganda designed to
deceive, to distract attention from economic reality so
as to promote the property and financial interests from
whose predatory grasp classical economists set out to
free the world. What is being attempted is nothing less
than an attempt to destroy the intellectual and moral
edifice of what took Western civilization eight
centuries to develop, from the 12th century Schoolmen
discussing Just Price through 19th and 20th century
classical economic value theory.
Any idea of “socialism from above,” in the sense of
“socializing the risk,” is old-fashioned oligarchy –
kleptocratic statism from above.
Real
nationalization occurs when governments act in the
public interest to take over private property. The
19th-century program to nationalize the land (it was the
first plank of the Communist Manifesto) did not
mean anything remotely like the government taking over
estates, paying off their mortgages at public expense
and then giving it back to the former landlords free and
clear of encumbrances and taxes. It meant taking the
land and its rental income into the public domain, and
leasing it out at a user fee ranging from actual
operating cost to a subsidized rate or even freely as in
the case of streets and roads.
Nationalizing the banks along these lines would mean
that the government would supply the nation’s credit
needs. The Treasury would become the source of new
money, replacing commercial bank credit. Presumably this
credit would be lent out for economically and socially
productive purposes, not merely to inflate asset prices
while loading down households and business with debt as
has occurred under today’s commercial bank lending
policies.
How neoliberals falsify the West’s political history
The fact that today’s neoliberals claim to be the
intellectual descendants of Adam Smith make it necessary
to restore a more accurate historical perspective. Their
concept of “free markets” is the antithesis of Smith’s.
It is the opposite of that of the classical political
economists down through John Stuart Mill, Karl Marx and
the Progressive Era reforms that sought to create
markets free of extractive rentier claims by
special interests whose institutional power can be
traced back to medieval Europe and its age of military
conquest.
Economic writers from the 16th through 20th centuries
recognized that free markets required government
oversight to prevent monopoly pricing and other charges
levied by special privilege. By contrast, today’s
neoliberal ideologues are public relations advocates for
vested interests to depict a “free market” is one free
of government regulation, “free” of anti-trust
protection, and even of protection against fraud, as
evidenced by the SEC’s refusal to move against Madoff,
Enron, Citibank et al.). The neoliberal ideal
of free markets is thus basically that of a bank robber
or embezzler, wishing for a world without police so as
to be sufficiently free to siphon off other peoples’
money without constraint.
The Chicago Boys in Chile realized that markets free for
predatory finance and insider privatization could only
be imposed at gunpoint. These free-marketers closed down
every economics department in Chile, every social
science department outside of the Catholic University
where the Chicago Boys held sway. Operation Condor
arrested, exiled or murdered tens of thousands of
academics, intellectuals, labor leaders and artists.
Only by totalitarian control over the academic
curriculum and public media backed by an active secret
police and army could “free markets” neoliberal style be
imposed. The resulting privatization at gunpoint became
an exercise in what Marx called “primitive accumulation”
– seizure of the public domain by political elites
backed by force. It is a free market
William-the-Conqueror or Yeltsin-kleptocrat style, with
property parceled out to the companions of the political
or military leader.
All this was just the opposite of the kind of free
markets that Adam Smith had in mind when he warned that
businessmen rarely get together but to plot ways to fix
markets to their advantage. This is not a problem that
troubled Mr. Greenspan or the editorial writers of the
New York Times and Washington Post. There really is no
kinship between their neoliberal ideals and those of the
Enlightenment political philosophers. For them to
promote an idea of free markets as ones “free” for
political insiders to pry away the public domain for
themselves is to lower an intellectual Iron Curtain on
the history of economic thought.
The classical economists and American Progressives
envisioned markets free of economic rent and interest –
free of rentier overhead charges and monopoly
price gouging, free of land-rent, interest paid to
bankers and wealthy financial institutions, and free of
taxes to support an oligarchy. Governments were to base
their tax systems on collecting the “free lunch” of
economic rent, headed by that of favorable locations
supplied by nature and given market value by public
investment in transportation and other infrastructure,
not by the efforts of landlords themselves.
The argument between Progressive Era reformers,
socialists, anarchists and individualists thus turned on
the political strategy of how best to free markets from
debt and rent. Where they differed was on the best
political means to achieve it, above all the role of the
state. There was broad agreement that the state was
controlled by vested interests inherited from feudal
Europe’s military conquests and the world that was
colonized by European military force. The political
question at the turn of the 20th century was whether
peaceful democratic reform could overcome the political
and even military resistance wielded by the Old Regime
using violence to retain its “rights.” The ensuing
political revolutions were grounded in the
Enlightenment, in the legal philosophy of men such as
John Locke, political economists such as Adam Smith,
John Stuart Mill and Marx. Power was to be used to free
markets from the predatory property and financial
systems inherited from feudalism. Markets were to be
free of privilege and free lunches, so that people would
obtain income and wealth only by their own labor and
enterprise. This was the essence of the labor theory of
value and its complement, the concept of economic rent
as the excess of market price over socially necessary
cost-value.
Although we now know that markets and prices, rent and
interest, contractual formalities and nearly all the
elements of economic enterprise originated in the “mixed
economies” of Mesopotamia in the fourth millennium BC
and continued throughout the mixed public/private
economies of classical antiquity, the discussion was so
politically polarized that the idea of a mixed economy
with checks and balances received scant attention a
century ago.
Individualists believed that all that shrinking central
governments would shrink the control mechanism by which
the vested interests extracted wealth without work or
enterprise of their own. Socialists saw that a strong
government was needed to protect society from the
attempts of property and finance to use their gains to
monopolize economic and political power. Both ends of
the political spectrum aimed at the same objective – to
bring prices down to actual costs of production. The
common aim was to maximize economic efficiency so as to
pass on the fruits of the Industrial and Agricultural
Revolutions to the population at large. This required
blocking the rentier class of interlopers from
grabbing the public domain and controlling the
allocation of resources. Socialists did not believe this
could be done without taking the state’s political and
legal power into their own hands. Marxists believed that
a revolution was necessary to reclaim property rent for
the public domain, and to enable governments to create
their own credit rather than borrow at interest from
commercial bankers and wealthy bondholders. The aim was
not to create a bureaucracy but to free society from the
surviving absentee ownership power of the vested
property and financial interests.
All this history of economic thought has been as
thoroughly expunged from today’s academic curriculum as
it has from popular discussion. Few people remember the
great debate at the turn of the 20th century: Would the
world progress fairly quickly from Progressive Era
reforms to outright socialism – public ownership of
basic economic infrastructure, natural monopolies
(including the banking system) and the land itself (and
to Marxists, of industrial capital as well)? Or, could
the liberal reformers of the day – individualists, land
taxers, classical economists in the tradition of Mill,
and American institutionalists such as Simon Patten –
retain capitalism’s basic structure and private property
ownership? If they could do so, they recognized that it
would have to be in the context of regulating markets
and introducing progressive taxation of wealth and
income. This was the alternative to outright “state”
ownership. Today’s extreme “free market” idea is a
dumbed-down caricature of this position.
All sides viewed the government as society’s “brain,”
its forward planning organ. Given the complexity of
modern technology, humanity would shape its own
evolution. Instead of evolution occurring by “primitive
accumulation,” it could be planned deliberately.
Individualists countered that no human planner was
sufficiently imaginative to manage the complexity of
markets, but endorsed the need to strip away all forms
of unearned income – economic rent and the rise in land
prices that Mill called the “unearned increment.” This
involved government regulation to shape markets. A “free
market” was an active political creation and required
regulatory vigilance.
As public relations advocates for the vested interests
and special rentier privilege, today’s
“neoliberal” advocates of “free” markets seek to
maximize economic rent – the free lunch of price in
excess of cost-value, not to free markets from
rentier charges. So misleading a pedigree only
could be achieved by outright suppression of knowledge
of what Locke, Smith and Mill really wrote. Attempts to
regulate “free markets” and limit monopoly pricing and
privilege are conflated with “socialism,” even with
Soviet-style bureaucracy. The aim is to deter the
analysis of what a “free market” really is: a market
free of unnecessary costs: monopoly rents, property
rents and financial charges for credit that governments
can create freely.
Political reform to bring market prices in line with
socially necessary cost-value was the great economic
issue of the 19th century. The labor theory of intrinsic
cost-value found its counterpart in the theory of
economic rent: land rent, monopoly price gouging,
interest and other returns to special privilege that
increased market prices purely by institutional property
claims. The discussion goes all the way back to the
medieval churchmen defining Just Price. The doctrine
originally was applied to the proper fees that bankers
could charge, and later was extended to land rent, then
to the monopolies that governments created and sold off
to creditors in an attempt to extricate themselves from
debt.
Reformists and more radical socialists alike sought to
free capitalism of its egregious inequities, above all
its legacy from Europe’s Dark Age of military conquest
when invading warlords seized lands and imposed an
absentee landlord class to receive the rental income,
which was used to finance wars of further land
acquisition. As matters turned out, hopes that
industrial capitalism could reform itself along
progressive lines to purge itself of its legacy from
feudalism have come crashing down. World War I hit the
global economy like a comet, pushing it into a new
trajectory and catalyzing its evolution into an
unanticipated form of finance capitalism.
It was unanticipated largely because most reformers
spent so much effort advocating progressive policies
that they neglected what Thorstein Veblen called the
vested interests. Their Counter-Enlightenment is
creating a world that would have been deemed a dystopia
a century ago – something so pessimistic that no
futurist dared depict a world run by venal and corrupt
bankers, protecting as their prime customers the
monopolies, real estate speculators and hedge funds
whose economic rent, financial gambling and asset-price
inflation is turned into a flow of interest in today’s
rentier economy. Instead of industrial
capitalism increasing capital formation we are seeing
finance capitalism strip capital, and instead of the
promised world of leisure we are being drawn into one of
debt peonage.
The financial travesty of democracy
The financial sector has redefined democracy by claiming
claims that the Federal Reserve must be “independent”
from democratically elected representatives, in order to
act as the bank lobbyist in Washington. This makes the
financial sector exempt from the democratic political
process, despite the fact that today’s economic planning
is now centralized in the banking system. The result is
a regime of insider dealings and oligarchy – rule by the
wealthy few.
The economic fallacy at work is that bank credit is a
veritable factor of production, an almost Physiocratic
source of fertility without which growth could not
occur. The reality is that the monopoly right to create
interest-bearing bank credit is a free transfer from
society to a privileged elite. The moral is that when we
see a “factor of production” that has no actual
labor-cost of production, it is simply an institutional
privilege.
So this brings us to the most recent debate about
“nationalizing” or “socializing” the banks. The Troubled
Asset Relief Program (TARP) so far has been used for the
following uses that I think can be truly deemed
anti-social, not “socialist” in any form.
By the end of last year, $20 billion was used to pay
bonuses and salaries to financial mismanagers, despite
the plunge of their banks into negative equity. And to
protect their interests, these banks continued to pay
lobbying fees to persuade legislators to give them yet
more special privileges.
While Citibank and other major institutions threatened
to bring the financial system crashing down by being
“too big to fail,” over $100 billion of TARP funds was
used to make them even bigger. Already teetering banks
bought affiliates that had grown by making irresponsible
and outright fraudulent loans. Bank of America bought
Angelo Mozilo’s Countrywide Financial and Merrill Lynch,
while JP Morgan Chase bought Bear Stearns and other big
banks bought WaMu and Wachovia.
Today’s policy is to “rescue” these giant bank
conglomerates by enabling them to “earn” their way out
of debt – by selling yet more debt to an already
over-indebted U.S. economy. The hope is to re-inflate
real estate and other asset prices. But do we really
want to let banks “pay back taxpayers” by engaging in
yet more predatory financial practices vis-à-vis the
economy at large? It threatens to maximize the margin of
market price over direct costs of production, by
building in higher financial charges. This is just the
opposite policy from trying to bring prices for housing
and infrastructure in line with technologically
necessary costs. It certainly is not a policy to make
the U.S. economy more globally competitive.
The Treasury’s plan to “socialize”
the banks, insurance companies and other financial
institutions is simply to step in and take bad loans off
their books, shifting the loss onto the public sector.
This is the antithesis of true nationalization or
“socialization” of the financial system. The banks and
insurance companies quickly got over their initial
knee-jerk fear that a government bailout would occur on
terms that would wipe out their bad management, along
with the stockholders and bondholders who backed this
bad management. The Treasury has assured these
mismanagers that “socialism” for them is a free gift.
The primacy of finance over the rest of the economy will
be affirmed, leaving management in place and giving
stockholders a chance to recover by earning more
from the economy at large, with yet more tax
favoritism. (This means yet heavier taxes shifted onto
consumers, raising their living costs accordingly.)
The bulk of wealth under capitalism – as under feudalism
–always has come primarily from the public domain,
headed by the land and formerly public utilities, capped
most recently by the Treasury’s debt-creating power. In
effect, the Treasury creates a new asset ($11 trillion
of new Treasury bonds and guarantees, e.g. the
$5.2 trillion to Fannie and Freddie). Interest on these
bonds is to be paid by new levies on labor, not on
property. This is what is supposed to re-inflate
housing, stock and bond prices – the money freed from
property and corporate taxes will be available to be
capitalized into yet new loans.
So the revenue hitherto paid as business taxes will
still be paid – in the form of interest – while the
former taxes will still be collected, but from labor.
The fiscal-financial burden thus will be doubled. This
is not a program to make the economy more competitive or
raise living standards for most people. It is a program
to polarize the U.S. economy even further between
finance, insurance and real estate (FIRE) at the top and
labor at the bottom.
Neoliberal denunciations of public regulation and
taxation as “socialism” is really an attack on classical
political economy – the “original” liberalism whose
ideal was to free society from the parasitic legacy of
feudalism. A truly socialized Treasury policy would be
for banks to lend for productive purposes that
contribute to real economic growth, not merely to
increase overhead and inflate asset prices by enough to
extract interest charges. Fiscal policy would aim to
minimize rather than maximizing the price of home
ownership and doing business, by basing the tax system
on collecting the rent that is now being paid out as
interest. Shifting the tax burden off wages and profits
onto rent and interest was the core of classical
political economy in the 18th and 19th centuries, as
well as the Progressive Era and Social Democratic reform
movements in the United States and Europe prior to World
War I. But this doctrine and its reform program has been
buried by the rhetorical smokescreen organized by
financial lobbyists seeking to muddy the ideological
waters sufficiently to mute popular opposition to
today’s power grab by finance capital and monopoly
capital. Their alternative to true nationalization and
socialization of finance is debt peonage, oligarchy and
neo-feudalism. They have called this program “free
markets.”
Michael Hudson is a former Wall Street
economist. A Distinguished Research Professor at
University of Missouri, Kansas City (UMKC), he is the
author of many books, including
Super Imperialism: The Economic Strategy of American
Empire (new ed., Pluto Press, 2002) He can be
reached via his website,
mh@michael-hudson.com
Source
 |